The main motivation for countries to join the WTO is their conviction that WTO membership will increase trade, help their economic development and foster economic growth. The WTO was created in 1995 based on terms negotiated between 128 original members. Subsequently, 36 new members have acceded under individual terms and conditions negotiated with existing members. Countries' import market power has been shown to be a key determinant of these terms and conditions (Bagwell and Staiger, 2011; Beshkar, Bond, and Rho, 2015; Beshkar and Lee, 2022). While GATT-WTO rounds of negotiation are seemingly static, the world is dynamic.
As countries develop, their share of world trade in different products will inevitably change, and so will their ability to affect world prices. This would imply that recurring rounds of trade negotiations would be helpful to maintain commitments at mutually acceptable levels or that commitments be conditioned on some measure of import market power. To our knowledge, we are the first to make this point in the economic policy literature, which has important implications for how multilateral rounds or commitments should be designed, and from a theoretical perspective, how these negotiations should be modelled.
Relying on a model by Bagwell and Staiger (2011) – arguably the most rigorous theoretical framework explaining countries' participation in international trade agreements – we provide novel estimates on the extent to which import market power has influenced tariff commitments for a set of original and acceded WTO members. We make use of a new dataset of pre-Uruguay Round applied tariffs in addition to standard data sources. Based on these estimates, we predict the commitments that might have been negotiated under current levels of market power. We estimate that tariff cuts required to reflect current economic conditions would amount to a reduction in annual tariff costs of up to $26.4 billion. Our results reveal substantial heterogeneity between countries and sectors. The sectors with the largest potential tariff cost reductions are vehicles (HS 87) and machinery and appliances (HS 84-85). Product-level reductions would range from 0 to 18.5 percentage points, with China featuring the largest average reductions.
Given the strong support in the literature for the importance of import market power in determining tariff bindings, we further argue that continuous rounds of trade negotiations are necessary owing to shifts in market power over time that, in part, may be endogenously determined by earlier rounds of liberalisation. Opening up to trade changes a country's pattern of specialisation and opens up potential for structural transformation at a pace and manner which are often difficult to predict. This implies that terms-of-trade externalities can arise in products where tariffs were initially set at a cooperative level.
相关报告
美国智库2.3万字报告:特朗普第二任总统任期的国际经济影响
1.2w+
类型:宏观
上传时间:2024-10
标签:贸易政策、移民、央行独立性)
语言:中英
金额:10元
美国智库万字报告-哪些美国盟友最有可能面临特朗普的关税 上架
1295
类型:宏观
上传时间:2025-01
标签:关税、政策建议)
语言:中英
金额:10元
WTO-2021年版世界关税概况报告(英)
760
类型:专题
上传时间:2021-07
标签:世界、关税)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
Currency Conflict and Trade Policy: A New Strategy for the United States《货币冲突与贸易政策——美国的新战略》
682
类型:电子书
上传时间:2020-08
标签:货币估值、贸易政策)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
CURRENCY CONFLICT AND TRADE POLICY《货币冲突与贸易政策——美国的新战略》
668
类型:电子书
上传时间:2020-09
标签:货币冲突、贸易政策)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
美国智库2万字报告-为什么特朗普的关税提案会伤害美国工薪阶层
654
类型:宏观
上传时间:2024-06
标签:关税、贸易战、政策影响)
语言:中英
金额:5元
联合国贸易发展委员会-贸易政策的主要统计和趋势2021(英)
539
类型:宏观
上传时间:2022-03
标签:贸易政策、趋势)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
国民经济研究局:贸易战中关税和不确定性对中国企业的影响(英)
528
类型:专题
上传时间:2020-10
标签:贸易战、关税、中国企业)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
牛津经济研究院-中国取消和提高关税对美国经济和就业的影响(英)
499
类型:专题
上传时间:2023-11
标签:关税、美国、就业)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
UNCTAD:通过可持续性公共采购和贸易政策提高自愿性可持续性标准(英)-2020.9
489
类型:专题
上传时间:2020-09
标签:公共采购、贸易政策)
语言:英文
金额:5积分
积分充值
30积分
6.00元
90积分
18.00元
150+8积分
30.00元
340+20积分
68.00元
640+50积分
128.00元
990+70积分
198.00元
1640+140积分
328.00元
微信支付
余额支付
积分充值
应付金额:
0 元
请登录,再发表你的看法
登录/注册